Editing Federal Reserve

From InfraWiki
Warning: You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you log in or create an account, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.

The edit can be undone. Please check the comparison below to verify that this is what you want to do, and then publish the changes below to finish undoing the edit.

Latest revision Your text
Line 55: Line 55:
Real power in the system resides with the New York Fed, which conducts Open Market Operations, implements monetary policy, and deals with all international relations. Over time this concentration of influence has diffused, but only slightly.  
Real power in the system resides with the New York Fed, which conducts Open Market Operations, implements monetary policy, and deals with all international relations. Over time this concentration of influence has diffused, but only slightly.  


At the first board meeting, '''Benjamin Strong''', a Morgan man and Jekyll Island attendee, was elected governor. He would spend the next fourteen years working tirelessly alongside '''Montagu Norman''', Governor of the Bank of England from 1920 to 1944, to reinstate an international gold standard. Norman - like the Morgans - was a Nazi collaborator and member of the Anglo-german fellowship. He funded the rearmament of Germany with loans, transferred gold from Czech to Nazi bank accounts,<ref>Blaazer, David (2005). "Finance and the End of Appeasement: The Bank of England, the National Government and the Czech Gold". ''Journal of Contemporary History''. '''40''' (1): 25–39.</ref> and was a close personal friend of nazi central bank leader, '''Hjalmar Schact'''.<ref>Forbes, Neil (2000), "Doing Business with the Nazis"</ref>
During the 1970s '''Petrodollar Recycling''' was largely handled through the New York Fed, with 30 percent of Saudi Arabia's total portfolio (70% of their US assets) held in a New York Fed account in 1978.<ref>David E. Spiro, ''The hidden hand of American hegemony: petrodollar recycling and international markets,'' 1999. p113</ref> This upset Arthur Bums, Chairman of the Board of Governors, who saw this as an attempt by the New York Fed to reassert dominance.<ref>David E. Spiro, ''The hidden hand of American hegemony: petrodollar recycling and international markets,'' 1999. p108</ref>


During the 1970s '''Petrodollar Recycling''' was largely handled through the New York Fed, with 30 percent of Saudi Arabia's total portfolio (70% of their US assets) held in a New York Fed account in 1978.<ref>David E. Spiro, ''The hidden hand of American hegemony: petrodollar recycling and international markets,'' 1999. p113</ref> This upset Arthur Burns, Chairman of the Board of Governors, who saw this as an attempt by the New York Fed to reassert dominance.<ref>David E. Spiro, ''The hidden hand of American hegemony: petrodollar recycling and international markets,'' 1999. p108</ref>  
At the first board meeting, '''Benjamin Strong''', a Morgan man and Jekyll Island attendee, was elected governor. He would spend the next fourteen years working tirelessly alongside '''Montagu Norman''', Governor of the Bank of England from 1920 to 1944, to reinstate an international gold standard. Norman - like the Morgans - was a Nazi collaborator and member of the Anglo-german fellowship. He funded the rearmament of Germany with loans, transferred gold from Czech to Nazi bank accounts,<ref>Blaazer, David (2005). "Finance and the End of Appeasement: The Bank of England, the National Government and the Czech Gold". ''Journal of Contemporary History''. '''40''' (1): 25–39.</ref> and was a close personal friend of nazi central bank leader, '''Hjalmar Schact'''.<ref>Forbes, Neil (2000), "Doing Business with the Nazis"</ref>  


=== Monetary Operations ===
=== Monetary Operations ===
Line 82: Line 82:
==== Requirement Ratio (Demand) ====
==== Requirement Ratio (Demand) ====
[[File:REQUIREMENT RATIO.png|thumb|301x301px|Requirement Ratio Diagram]]
[[File:REQUIREMENT RATIO.png|thumb|301x301px|Requirement Ratio Diagram]]
Open Market Operations and the Discount Rate effect supply, but the Federal Reserve has two more methods, each effecting demand. First, they can change the '''requirement ratio''', which is the amount of reserves banks are required to keep in the with the fed. Because these reserves cannot be used for investment, ''increasing the required reserves '''increases demand,''' shifts demand for funds right, lowering the federal funds rate'' (increasing liquidity), or vice-versa.
Open Market Operations and the Discount Rate effect supply, but the Federal Reserve has two more methods, each effecting demand. First, they can change the '''requirement ratio''', which is the amount of reserves banks are required to keep in the with the fed. Because these reserves cannot be used for investment, ''increasing the required reserves '''increases demand,''' shifts demand for funds right, lowering the federal funds rate'', and vice-versa.


==== Interest on Reserves (Demand) ====
==== Interest on Reserves (Demand) ====
[[File:INTEREST ON RESERVES1.png|thumb|330x330px|Interest on Reserves Diagram]]
[[File:INTEREST ON RESERVES1.png|thumb|258x258px|Interest on Reserves Diagram]]
Another way to affect demand is by changing interest on reserves. Until 2008, the Federal Reserve did not pay interest on reserves banks held with them. First authorized by Congress 2006 with implementation scheduled for 2011, the program was fast tracked in response to the crisis. This was pursuant of Fed policy: buying up toxic assets while minimizing the effect this would traditionally have had on general liquidity. Fed officials feared the federal funds rate would dip below their target and cause price instability. <blockquote>To avoid this outcome, the Fed "sterilized" the effect of liquidity injections on the overall economy: It sold an equal amount in Treasury securities from its own account to banks. Sterilization offset the injections' effect on the monetary base and therefore the overall supply of credit, keeping the total supply of reserves largely unchanged and the fed funds rate at its target. Sterilization reduced the amount in Treasury securities that the Fed held on its balance sheet by roughly 40 percent in a year's time, from over $790 billion in July 2007 to just under $480 billion by June 2008. However, following the failure of Lehman Brothers and the rescue of American International Group in September 2008, credit market dislocations intensified and lending through the Fed's new lending facilities ballooned. The Fed no longer held enough Treasury securities to sterilize the lending.
Another way to affect demand is by changing interest on reserves. Until 2008, the Federal Reserve did not pay interest on reserves banks held with them, when it was introduced as an additional form of leverage. Paying interest on reserves allows the Fed to place a floor on the federal funds rate (the horizontal line in the supply curve), because banks have little reason to lend at rates below the rate of interest they receive on their reserve balances. The rate is determined by the Board of Governors.
 
 
This led the Fed to request authority to accelerate implementation of the IOR policy that had been approved in 2006. Once banks began earning interest on the excess reserves they held, they would be more willing to hold on to excess reserves instead of attempting to purge them from their balance sheets via loans made in the fed funds market, which would drive the fed funds rate below the Fed's target for that rate. When the Fed stopped sterilizing its liquidity injections, the monetary base (which is comprised of total reserves in the banking system plus currency in circulation) ballooned in line with Fed lending, from about $847 billion in August 2008 to almost $2 trillion by October 2009. However, this did not result in a proportional increase in the overall money supply (Figure 1). This result is likely due largely to an undesirable lending environment: Banks likely found it more desirable to hold excess reserves in their accounts at the Fed, earning the IOR rate with zero risk, given that there were few attractive lending opportunities. That the liquidity injections did not result in a proportional increase in the money supply may also be due to banks' increased demand to hold liquid reserves (as opposed to individually lending those excess reserves out) in the wake of the financial crisis<ref>The Effect of Interest on Reserves on Monetary Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, 2009[https://web.archive.org/web/20231004123632/https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2009/eb_09-12#:~:text=On%20October%2013%2C%202006%2C%20the,%2C%20to%20October%201%2C%202008. https://web.archive.org/web/20231004123632/https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2009/eb_09-12#:~:text=On%20October%2013%2C%202006%2C%20the,%2C%20to%20October%201%2C%202008.]</ref></blockquote>In the graph, IOR allows the Fed to place a floor on the federal funds rate (the horizontal line in the supply curve), because banks have little reason to lend at rates below the rate of interest they receive on their reserve balances. The rate is determined by the Board of Governors.


==== Extraordinary Measures (2008) ====
==== Extraordinary Measures (2008) ====
Please note that all contributions to InfraWiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see Meta:Copyrights for details). Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel Editing help (opens in new window)